Is It Better to Starve?

in #politics8 years ago

There's no ethical consumption under global capitalism... or is there?

The subtext of many contemporary works against capitalism is that it encourages death, destruction, gloom, and doom. Modern collectivists and protectionists - people who argue for market regulation either through communal or state regulation - paint a picture of capitalism as a market structure that ultimately wants to push the masses into poverty, leaving them starving and sick, so that a few people can live in abject luxury.

I think the argument, at its core, hints at a good discussion to be had. Does a free market cause scarcity? And, counter, does a protected market encourage abundance?

Before we can dive into a discussion about those answers, I think it's important to stop and answer a more fundamental question.

What's better for humanity: scarcity or abundance?

It sounds like a silly question, doesn't it? Who has ever suggested that scarcity would be better?
A lot of people, actually. It's implicit in many statements from politicians, journalists, and even economists and corporate executives.

"Cheap Chinese goods are hurting American workers," implies that an abundance of goods is bad for domestic laborers.

"Immigrants take away our jobs," implies that an abundance of labor would be bad.

"3D printing will kill industry," implies a shortage of goods would be preferred.

We see politicians advocate for import tariffs, reducing the availability of goods. This does far more than imply that scarcity is desirable; it makes scarcity an economic mandate.

It's not often that these issues are constructed in terms of abundance and scarcity. When they are, it's clear the goal of many collectivist and protectionist measures is to establish and maintain a scarcity. How did so many people arrive at the idea that scarcity is an advantage, and abundance terrifying?

digital art respresenting the dichotomy of production and consumption
Is it better to guide a market, or let it protect itself?

Supply & Demand

Let's look at when scarcity is preferred. Basic economics states that a good is more valuable when supply is low and demand is high. Applied to a labourer, this means they see personal advantage in a market where the labour they provide is scarce. Extrapolated out to labour collectively, labour is more valuable when it is scarce. This supports the notion that the market should be protected against an abundance of labour.

The same laws of supply & demand outline that if a product is abundant, it is sold for a lower price, and the producer earns less. If every product is abundant, every producer is earning less. Again, abundance is dangerous and scarcity beneficial from the perspective of producers. It does not matter whether the product is a good or service or the labour that provides the product.

But this is an incomplete view of a market. Labourers do not produce simply for the sake of producing. We produce to meet the demand of consumers. The outline so far completely discounts the consumption - or demand - side of the market, looking only at the production - or supply. It reduces humanity to only a producer, who becomes richer as he sells things for more.

The necessarily correlation is that, as consumers, we become richer as we buy things for less. This is, conveniently (and by necessity) the inverse of our producer.

We established that, from the perspective of a producer, scarcity is preferred. But from the perspective of a consumer, the exact opposite is true: the more abundance in the market, the more they are able to buy.
Put yet another way, as producers/suppliers/sellers, we are interested in high prices (scarcity), and as consumers/demanders/buyers, we are interested in low prices (abundance).

Each person is a producer in some cases - when they're at work - and a consumer in others - when they're at the grocery. So why is so much economic discussion focused only on the role of producers in the market, treating consumers as an implicit effect of production, not an equal (or perhaps more important) force?

The Producer/Consumer Binary

This may all seem too simple to even be worth discussion, but as I stated in the introduction, I'm trying to disprove some assumptions people have about markets that just don't hold up if we outline the specifics like we're doing. So bear with me.

So far we've established that there are two sides to self-interest in economics: a desire for scarcity in what you provide, and a desire for abundance in what you consume.

Now let's move on to the next question: is one of these sides of our self-interest more in line with the general and permanent interest of humanity? It should be clear we can't decide whether scarcity or abundance is better from the perspective of an individual participant in the market, since that's situational depending on which side of the transaction we're on. One party might find high prices advantageous where another might find them ruinous. So, how can we prove whether scarcity or abundance is ultimately better for humanity?

the interplay of agents in a market
Every person has multiple connections to other parts of the economy.

For the Greater Good

In order to establish a more neutral "good," let's look at what the consequences are when a producer and consumer each see their desires met. I'm going to use healthcare as the example, mostly because it is a currently popular issue in economics.

A producer of health care, a doctor, is hurt by every advancement that increases the supply of medical care and reduces the demand. Convincing people not to smoke, 3D printing cartilage, and organ transplants are all harmful to the doctor, as an economic agent. This isn't to say anyone working in medicine actively desires disease run rampant, but that illness maintains a demand for what they supply. So to a doctor, scarcity of health is desirable.

If you make cars, you would want foreign vehicles to face heavy tariffs. This would raise their price without raising their value, inducing scarcity, and protect the price of your domestic vehicles. Producers of diamond jewelry want a scarcity of knowledge about gem mining (no one wants to know they're buying a blood diamond), soldiers want scarcity of peace, farmers want scarcity of food, and so on.

The Producer Perspective

From the perspective of the producer, scarcity is desirable. But that would also mean a lack of healthcare, a lack of cars, a lack of jewelry, a lack of safety, a lack of food, and so on. Delivering on the desires of the producers leads to market-wide scarcity, which in turn leads to higher costs for all goods, meaning practical inflation.

The most strong non-contemporary Western example of this is the period from ~1530 until ~1760. Prices during that time increased by an average of 1.2% each year. (There were periods of deflation, but due to protectionist market regulation, periods of acute inflation, sometimes as much as 20% annually.)

While a 1.2% inflation rate is quite low by contemporary standards, it was very high compared to the periods before and after, until the end of World War I when protectionism became a common government economic activity. (What we think of as a "normal economy" is only about 100 years old - until that period, most of the world's economy was self-regulating.)

So scarcity of production, while desirable for the producer, results in a steady reduction of supply to maintain prices, which means at a human level, less food, shelter, medicine, etc. Hardly seems like an ideal situation for the future of humanity, and yet is the normal course of action under collectivist or protectionist markets.

The Consumer Perspective

Contrast this with what happens when the consumer is given what they want, an abundant supply, and low demand. From the perspective of a consumer, the market should be perfectly supplied; abundance in all things. Food, shelter, education, and healthcare should all be available so cheaply that the consumer can obtain them at very low costs. There are several ways to get to this sort of abundance. The historic shortcut was to go to war and steal what others had, creating localized abundance. More recently, we favoured colonialism, and now many nations practice neocolonialism to secure abundance.

That doesn't mean this theft shortcut is necessary, and in a global economy, it's hardly a shortcut at all, considering it leaves the other side with severe scarcity. (This was always the case, but prior to a global economy system, it didn't affect the people doing the stealing.)

So far, compared to scarcity, abundance seems like the way to go. The downside of this abundance is that, with a perfectly supplied market, there is no demand for a person's labour, and this leaves them without an income with which to buy what they need, no matter how cheap they might be.

In reality, this is actually the greatest strength of a market striving for abundance. Without an abundance of production, humanity may turn its labour toward meeting more and more complicated of obstacles. While we currently struggle with providing the market with all the food and medicine it needs, if these things were provided in abundance, we could move on to further innovations and meet more complex of perceived needs. This has been the general trend of labour since societies began to form, however, we have frequently allowed our desire for high incomes to get in the way of our desire for low prices.

The desires of the producers, to have high incomes, are inherently antisocial. They require a lack of supply in the things humanity needs. The desires of the consumers are pro-social, resulting in an abundance of the things humanity needs, and enabling us to provide for our wants.

Resolving the Binary

For quite some time, I've been talking about consumers and producers as two separate entities. It's important to remember that each person is both - a person produces when they labour, and consumes when they overcome the innate obstacles of living. A consumer with an abundantly supplied market has less demanded of them in an exchange. This "less demand" translates to an ability to produce less, as they need less to fill their needs. This "produce less" in turn leads to reducing the supply of labour, curbing the abundance which reduced costs, raising them to an equilibrium point, or leads to the labour being redirected to another market, overcoming another obstacle. These two potentials for labour bring us closer to a market where supply is met perfectly, and at zero cost, at a benefit to the consumer self-interest we all have, leading to humanitarian prosperity.

a market seeks a route to equillibrium
A market seeks equilibrium

Do Capitalists Want Scarcity?

At the start of this article, I asked whether a free market encouraged scarcity and whether a protected market encouraged abundance. I then asked whether scarcity or abundance is preferable, for humanity at large.

I've demonstrated that fulfilling the desires of each person as a consumer ultimately leads to a scarcity which does indeed encourage starvation and sickness. However, I've also demonstrated that this desire for scarcity only exists in contrast to our consumer desire for abundance, which ultimately is more beneficial to humanity at large. Therefore, abundance is preferable.
It is only when a protective agent intervenes that the desires of the producer are placed above the desires of a consumer, and scarcity is constructed as the preferred, or at the least, equally desired outcome.
This leaves us with two possible interpretations. Either one acknowledges that market regulation, through either protectionism or collectivism, protects scarcity, or one denies it.

If one acknowledges the protection of scarcity, one acknowledges that this protection also protects the existence of hunger, sickness, war, and so on.

If one denies it, you deny it is protective of supply at all, and deny any benefits it has for producers, even ignoring the detrimental effects it has on consumers and humanity.

Either collectivism and protectionism are harmful, or useless.

All images created by the author; header image modified from image originally found in Boxun Beijeng online newspaper

Sort:  

Hello emsenn, we would like to inform you that you have been chosen as a featured author by the @robinhoodwhale initiave.

More about Robin Hood Whale

Interesting Post - Keep on Steeming!

Thank you very much! I woke up seeing the post had gained some traction and jumped out of bed to see why.

Since the Industrial Revolution we have been tending toward abundance. The Free Market works every where it's been tried and it works best when it's the most free. It works less well when it's less free so the concept of 'regulating' the market is just stupid. An organization's collective IQ is inversely proportional to the number of members it has and the Government is the largest organization.

Think about it.

I did think about it. Then I wrote this piece. :P

I don't know if I buy the notion of "collective IQ," though, and even if I did, a market would be the largest collective, it just wouldn't be a cohesive collective the way a state would be.

The market is not an organization so it does not have a collective IQ.

Steemian
Steem On

Interesting article. I am a post scarcity anarchist. I see no problem with combining abundance with a post capitalist society. The solution is simple. Production of goods and services will be automated to a very high degree.

And then you give stuff away,for free.

Yes,you heard it right. Do away with both capitalism,and the monetary system.
Certain things will still be scarce,mostly attention. And "services" or functions involving human consciousness,like a therapist,or a teacher.

We should do these remaining tasks on a voluntary basis.

Alternatively,what I see as a transitonal step, and this is quite likely to happen organically,most goods and servises could be produced at extremely low costs,by cooperatively owned local manufactoring technology,and certain things that are still scarce will be traded. Cooperative ownership is on the rise,and is being helped with possibilities like DAOs and smart contracts.
Your argument that market regulations protects scarcity is valid at the current moment,in some situations.
It might be more difficult to realise that capitalist monopolies are also creating artificial scarcity,and stifling innovation. The digital age has greatly increased the problem of monopolies.
In addition, public spending is crucial to scientific progress,and techological innovation. And innovation drives abundance,not just market factors.So many innovations are based on public research,funded by tax money. Like the iphone.
http://time.com/4089171/mariana-mazzucato/

Good thoughts. I'd love to see us reach that post-scarcity point. To be honest, once we do, I don't think it'll matter what market model we use, since a large part of economics is meant to handle scarcity. Just like a person on an island doesn't need economics due to a lack of other people, a person who has everything they need in basically infinite supply doesn't either.

I agree with you that a large part of the problem with what I've outlined, outside of theory, is the issue of corporate hegemony reinforced by the same market protections I argue against. My post doesn't deal with it at all (perhaps for a future writeup?) but even if we were to completely shift away from collectivism/protectionism, the corporations which have been benefited to date would still be able to maintain control of the market, regardless of future actions.

Regarding public spending being crucial to innovation, I disagree. Innovation of the scale we saw through the 20th century was more a factor of manhours being devoted to a project. While the abundance of manhours came from government spending, I think it's false to argue that it needs to.

Thanks for your comment!

I think a lot of confusion stems from real income versus nominal income. If wages drop, but prices drop further you are better off. If protectionism increases wages but also prices, no gain is made. You cannot legislate prosperity. But many don't see it this way as they think in nominal terms. While you may think you can somehow get protectionism for your particular industry and none other, this is never going to happen. You are never the only one trying to get advantages.

The free market does not cause scarcity. That is why protectionism is sought after.

I'm in favor of leveling the playing field. It's not really a question of abundance vs scarcity for me. The problem as I see it is that there are opposing forces each getting bills passed that have​ caused the employment & economic problems we have today. For example, free trade vs higher taxes. That gives double the incentive to not only to move production overseas but also move part or all of a companies operation overseas.

Add to that the costs of operation that are steadily rising as more state/federal compliance regulations, licensing, and such are added every year. It's no wonder US corporations are jumping ship. We're also one of the few countries still trying to tax foreign profits as well. In doing so the government has created loopholes to dodge paying taxes on income generated domestically. But that's another topic.

Using tariffs to level the playing field isn't a bad idea, it's just a bad idea to do it in such a way that causes scarcity. Also, just raising tariffs alone will not solve the problem.

I'm more of a conservative and I believe that income inequality is real. I just see it as a product of years of government, state and federal, manipulation that has stifled competition.

I agree 100% with your comment, and it's part of why I took such a long time to highlight that protectionism doesn't actually encourage abundance.

I touch on it in my reply to @kooshikoo, but the issue I don't address in this post at all is that even if we as a culture and society were to suddenly give up our obsession with market regulation, those who have seen their interests protected for the last century would have the resources to continue to protect themselves, at this point.

I see a lot of economic conservatives lead this to them thinking we should have a transitionary period where the regulations bias toward the consumer, not producer. However, I don't see that as any guarantee against continued reinforcement of the current hegemony.

I think the only thing truly helping are projects like Steemit and other emergent value markets, which simply don't require participation in the mainstream market for their own valuation to be real. But, that's a long thought probably better saved for a fresh post.

Thanks for reading!

I enjoyed this post, but as a "producer" (I own a small business), I think you may have this understanding a little off:

From the perspective of the producer, scarcity is desirable.

For me, it's not "scarcity" that is desirable, but meeting real human needs in a way that isn't currently being met by the market. You may think that's a semantic difference, but I see it as a significant one. I enjoyed Peter Thiel's book Zero to One because he highlights the benefits of natural monopolies. If you're providing a service to consumers at such an amazing level there's no waste or room for someone else to join that market, they are then free to go create a brand new market and meet new needs which benefit humanity. The moment someone is wasteful, they are replaced by some other actor who can do things more efficiently at a better price and quality (assuming no protectionism). To paint producers as simply working to secure scarcity puts a lot of this post into a false dichotomy situation (IMO) when there are really many types of producers taking many different angles on how to best meet the needs of consumers in the marketplace.

Either way, it's refreshing to see more than just a "Grrrr Capitalism BAD! Grrrr" post. :)

Coin Marketplace

STEEM 0.28
TRX 0.13
JST 0.032
BTC 61285.21
ETH 2922.72
USDT 1.00
SBD 3.66